Thinking back on the last couple
of
posts, a couple of questions arise naturally. First, there is the question
of the survival of regimes in general, not just democracy: if most democracies
die within 15 years or so, what is the median duration (the “half-life,” if you will: the time
it takes for half of them to be gone) of other regimes? And second, there is
the question of the relationship between the half-life of regimes and the
half-life of leaders: do regimes whose leaders tend to have longer half-lives also
have longer half-lives? My interest in these questions stems from my current
research on the question of legitimacy: my sense is that legitimacy matters
much less than people usually think to the survival of large-scale patterns of
political power and authority, so I’m interested in trying to figure out if
there are systematic differences in survival between more and less “legitimate”
regimes and other political structures. So this is another exploratory post,
with lots of graphs.
How do we measure the duration of non-democratic
regimes relative to democratic regimes? Though democratic regimes are not
always straightforward to identify, non-democratic regimes come in a much wider
variety of forms – from hereditary, absolute monarchies to single party regimes
and multiparty hybrids, and some of these forms shade gradually into one
another over the course of many years. (For a sense of this variety, consider
the differences between Mexico before the 1990s under the PRI, whose presidents
succeeded each other with clockwork regularity every six years and a lively opposition
existed but could never win the presidency, North Korea today, where opposition
is non-existent and succession is controlled by a tiny clique, and Mubarak’s
Egypt.) To get a handle on this question, I’m going to use the Polity IV dataset,
which codes “authority characteristics” in all independent countries (with
population greater than 500,000 people) from 1800 to 2010. (I’ve been convinced
by Jay Ulfelder’s work that the
DD dataset I used in
my earlier post is not appropriate to study comparative regime survival due
to the way it codes certain democracies where alternation in power has not
occurred as dictatorships, which systematically biases the survival estimates
of democracies upwards).
The Polity dataset is fairly rich. Most researchers
seem to use only the composite indexes of democracy and dictatorship it offers,
but these indexes, while useful, do not have a strong theoretical motivation,
as Cheibub, Gandhi, and Vreeland argue
here. For my purposes, it is best to use the dataset to extract those authority
characteristics of political regimes it purports to measure: the mechanisms of
executive recruitment, the type of political competition, and the degree of
executive constraint. Mechanisms of
executive recruitment include hereditary selection, hybrid forms combining
hereditary and electoral mechanisms, selection by small elites, rigged elections,
irregular forms of seizing power, and competitive elections; types of political
competition range from the repressed (all opposition banned, as in North Korea)
to the open (typical of thriving democracies); and executive constraints range
from unlimited to “parity” with the legislature. (See the Polity IV codebook
for a full discussion). In theory, the dataset distinguishes eight kinds of
executive recruitment mechanisms, ten types of political competition, and seven degrees of executive constraint, plus three
different kinds of “interruption” (including breakdowns of state authority,
loss of independence, and foreign invasion and occupation), leading to a
possible 563 possible patterns of political authority, but these dimensions are
all highly correlated (over .99); indeed, only 212 combinations of executive
recruitment, political competition, and executive constraint actually appear in
the date, most of them only once and for short periods of time, and it is
obvious that some combinations do not even make sense. (And those that do make
sense do not always capture all the information we would normally want about a
political regime: Polity has no good measure for the extent of suffrage in
competitive regimes, for example). But the dataset helpfully indicates how long
each of these patterns last, so we can attempt a first cut at the question of
the half life of regimes using a Kaplan-Meier graph:
The half-life of an “authority pattern” – a combination
of an executive recruitment mechanism, a type of political competition, and a
specific form of executive constraint – is 6.6 years, though the tail of the
distribution is very long: some of them have lasted for upwards of a century. Switzerland,
for example, has had the same authority pattern for 162 years, and Afghanistan
retained the same authority pattern from 1800 to 1935 (a hereditary monarchy). As
it happens, social and political life comes to be mostly structured in most
places by the long-lasting patterns, but most
patterns of authority do not last that long. Incidentally, at this level of
abstraction there are no great regional differences in the half-lives of
authority patterns, though it does seem as if authority patterns last slightly longer
in Europe and the Americas than in Africa and Asia:
Yet an “authority pattern” is too amorphous
a unit of analysis. We might get a better handle on the question of comparative
regime survival by looking specifically at the mechanism of executive selection,
since the manner in which the chief power in the state is selected is normally
thought to be quite important and to have far-reaching consequences: whether
supreme power is achievable by hereditary succession only or through designation
within a closed elite or via competitive elections or some other means seems to
have important consequences.
Of all the mechanisms of executive selection
identified in the Polity IV dataset, only one, “Competitive Elections,” is
unambiguously democratic by most people’s lights. Though within the dataset the
fact that a regime has competitive elections is no guarantee that it will also
have universal suffrage, for the most part “competitive elections” identifies most
countries that most people think are democratic. We can thus calculate the
duration of all periods of “competitive elections” and compare them to the
duration of all “non-democratic” periods – those periods where executive selection
happened through some other means. The details are somewhat tricky (see the
code), but here are the results:
Some notes. As we might have expected from
the discussion in the
previous post, full hereditary monarchies (Russia under the Tsars, Saudi
Arabia, Iran under the Shah, Portugal and Romania in the 19th
century, Nepal in the 19th century, among others; there are 65
episodes in 40 countries in the dataset) have the longest half-lives (nearly 32
years; this increases if we collapse the two hereditary monarchy categories.
Note these are not “constitutional” monarchies like the British one). But competitive
electoral regimes are no slouches, with a half-life of about 17 years (in
keeping with Jay’s numbers in
this post, though he uses a different dataset), and as time goes on their
survival rates seem to converge with those of monarchies. Similarly, “limited
elite selection regimes” (e.g., single party-communist regimes, where a narrow
clique selects the leader without open competition) have a half-life comparable
to that of democracies, but as time goes on they tend to break down more; their
survival rates seem to diverge from those of competitive electoral and
monarchical regimes. Low survival rates are found especially among political
forms that appear to have internal tensions, such as competitive
authoritarian regimes, where elections exist and are contested by an
opposition, but it is very hard for the opposition to attain real power (e.g.,
Zimbabwe today). I confess I don’t really understand Polity’s “Executive-guided
transition” category, but it’s obviously a regime that is turning into
something else (the Pinochet regime in Chile after the 1980 referendum but before the return of competitive elections counts, for example), and “ascription
plus election” includes regimes where the monarch retains some real power but
the legislature and other executive offices are no longer under its thumb (only a few are recorded in the data,
including Belgium in the late 19th century and Nepal in the 1980s
and 90s); it makes sense that such regimes, halfway between “real” monarchies
and purely constitutional monarchies like the British, should have short
half-lives as the conflict plays out and either turn into competitive electoral
regimes or into more absolute monarchies.
It is also interesting to compare the
relative survival rates of competitive electoral patterns of authority vis a vis periods where selection
happens by non-competitive electoral means (regardless of whether the selection means stay the same):
Though the difference seems to narrow as
time passes, the half-life of non-democracy since the 19th century
has been a bit longer than the half-life of competitive electoral regimes (23
vs. 17 years). In sum, political regimes do not last much more than a
generation.
(For those still following, the regional
breakdown indicates that competitive electoral periods have had the longest
half-lives in Europe and the Americas, whereas non-democracy has had the
longest half-lives in Africa and Asia; no special surprises there, though I am not sure about the reason).
How does this relate to the half-life of
leaders? For that, we turn to the ARCHIGOS dataset by Goemans,
Gleditsch, and Chiozza, which contains information about the entry and exit
date of almost all political leaders of independent countries in the period 1840-2010.
It’s a fantastic resource – more than 3000 leader episodes, and information on
their manner of exit and entry. And the conclusion one must draw from examining
it is that power is extremely hard to
hold on to; a ruler’s hold on power seems to decay in an exponential manner
(note I haven’t checked that the decay really is exponential in the technical
sense, though I'm thinking of doing that). Over this vast span of time, covering all kinds of political regimes, the
half-life of leaders is only about 2 years, or a third of the median authority
pattern, as we might have expected from the previous post (though the half-life
of leaders is even smaller here):
Yet of course it is the people who beat the
odds – those who last much longer than the average leader – the ones who shape
social and political life. (There’s an endless parade of mediocrities in the dataset, two-bit prime ministers gone after a few months of ineffectual dabbling and the like).
(But don’t some leaders come back to power
after losing it? In fact, the vast majority of leaders only attain power once, and never return
to power, though about 100 did manage the feat three or more times. In fact,
practice does not help; survival in power only appears to decrease the more previous times the leader had been in power,
though note that the uncertainty of the estimates also increases, and one might
expect that age would take its toll too).
We are now in a position to extend the analysis in the post below by merging the Archigos and the Polity
dataset to calculate the survival curves for leaders conditional on the pattern
of executive recruitment. Though I would take these curves with a grain of salt,
here are the results:
As expected from the previous post, it’s good to be king
– the half-life of absolute kings is about 12 years (and it’s almost always
king: there are only 41 female leaders in a 3000 case dataset). Interestingly, a
similar result for the half-lives of Chinese emperors is reported
here (10 years: Khmaladze, Brownrigg, and Haywood 2010, ungated)
as well as for the
half-lives of Roman emperors (11 years: Khmaladze, Brownrigg, and Haywood 2007, ungated).
There is something about the deep structure of monarchies in many different
periods and societies, it seems, that points to a half-life in power of about 10-13 years
for monarchs.
More generally, authoritarianism pays in terms
of leader tenure, despite the fact that non-competitive regimes do not always last longer than competitive ones. The highest
half-lives of leaders beyond monarchs are found in limited elite selection
regimes, executive-guided transitions (where non-democratic leaders are
changing the rules), and competitive authoritarian regimes; but democracies are
more lasting than most of these regimes (except for monarchies; see above).
Another way of looking at this is to calculate what we
might call the “personalization quotient” of a regime: divide the half-life of
the leader (for a given regime) by the half-life of the regime to get an idea
of the percentage of the regime half-life that a leader is expected to last. So
a monarch is expected to last about 37% of the half-life his regime (31.86 /
12); this is the most intensely personalized of regimes, as one might have
expected given that it is devoted to the maintenance of a family line. The
next most personalized regimes are competitive authoritarian regimes (28%), “self-selection”
regimes (15%), limited elite selection regimes (16%), and “executive-guided
transitions” (40%; this is pretty much by definition, however, so I don't make much of them). A competitive
electoral regime has a personalization quotient of 8% - an expected leader half-life of about 2, divided by an expected regime duration of about 17 years. From the point of view
of such a leader, it pays to try to move towards a competitive authoritarian
regime, and it pays for the leader of a limited elite selection regime to move
towards a formal hereditary monarchy (as is happening, in a sense, in North
Korea right now, and almost happened in Egypt and Libya).
But are authoritarian regimes more risky, so that leaders will try to hang on to power more? We can also look at that using the archigos dataset. Though leaders in non-democratic regimes have a slightly higher risk of leaving office with their heads on pitchforks or hanging from lampposts, the vast majority leave by "regular" procedures.
More, perhaps, could be said. I’ve been wondering, for
example, about whether there is a relationship between the breakdown of
particular regimes and the tenure of leaders, though I’m not sure how to go
about tackling that question. From the point of view
of the study of legitimacy, however, what strikes me is the general fragility
of patterns of authority and rule: few patterns of authority are expected have
half-lives that exceed a single generation, and most don’t last nearly as long,
regardless of their “legitimation formula” – heredity, competitive elections,
ideology, whatever. Of course, some beat the odds, especially some competitive
regimes and some monarchies, and these shape history. But the historical
evidence suggests that they are in a sense the exception rather than the rule.
Code necessary for replicating the graphs in this post,
plus further ideas for analysis, here and here. You will need to download the Polity IV and ARCHIGOS datasets
directly, and this file of codes from my repository.
[Update: fixed some typos, 9 Feb 2012]
[Update: fixed some typos, 9 Feb 2012]